Itô's lemma

From The Right Wiki
(Redirected from Ito's lemma)
Jump to navigationJump to search

In mathematics, Itô's lemma or Itô's formula (also called the Itô–Doeblin formula, especially in the French literature) is an identity used in Itô calculus to find the differential of a time-dependent function of a stochastic process. It serves as the stochastic calculus counterpart of the chain rule. It can be heuristically derived by forming the Taylor series expansion of the function up to its second derivatives and retaining terms up to first order in the time increment and second order in the Wiener process increment. The lemma is widely employed in mathematical finance, and its best known application is in the derivation of the Black–Scholes equation for option values. Kiyoshi Itô published a proof of the formula in 1951.[1]

Motivation

Suppose we are given the stochastic differential equation dXt=μtdt+σtdBt, where Bt is a Wiener process and the functions μt,σt are deterministic (not stochastic) functions of time. In general, it's not possible to write a solution Xt directly in terms of Bt. However, we can formally write an integral solution Xt=0tμsds+0tσsdBs. This expression lets us easily read off the mean and variance of Xt (which has no higher moments). First, notice that every dBt individually has mean 0, so the expected value of Xt is simply the integral of the drift function: E[Xt]=0tμsds. Similarly, because the dB terms have variance 1 and no correlation with one another, the variance of Xt is simply the integral of the variance of each infinitesimal step in the random walk: Var[Xt]=0tσs2ds. However, sometimes we are faced with a stochastic differential equation for a more complex process Yt, in which the process appears on both sides of the differential equation. That is, say dYt=a1(Yt,t)dt+a2(Yt,t)dBt, for some functions a1 and a2. In this case, we cannot immediately write a formal solution as we did for the simpler case above. Instead, we hope to write the process Yt as a function of a simpler process Xt taking the form above. That is, we want to identify three functions f(t,x),μt, and σt, such that Yt=f(t,Xt) and dXt=μtdt+σtdBt. In practice, Ito's lemma is used in order to find this transformation. Finally, once we have transformed the problem into the simpler type of problem, we can determine the mean and higher moments of the process.

Derivation

We derive Itô's lemma by expanding a Taylor series and applying the rules of stochastic calculus. Suppose Xt is an Itô drift-diffusion process that satisfies the stochastic differential equation

dXt=μtdt+σtdBt,

where Bt is a Wiener process. If f(t,x) is a twice-differentiable scalar function, its expansion in a Taylor series is

Δf(t)dtdt=f(t+dt,x)f(t,x)=ftdt+122ft2(dt)2++
Δf(x)dxdx=f(t,x+dx)f(t,x)=fxdx+122fx2(dx)2+

Then use the total derivative and the definition of the partial derivative fy=limdy0Δf(y)dy:

df=ftdt+fxdx=limdx0,dt0ftdt+122ft2(dt)2++fxdx+122fx2(dx)2+.

Substituting x=Xt and therefore dx=dXt=μtdt+σtdBt, we get

df=limdBt0,dt0ftdt+122ft2(dt)2++fx(μtdt+σtdBt)+122fx2(μt2(dt)2+2μtσtdtdBt+σt2(dBt)2)+.

In the limit dt0, the terms (dt)2 and dtdBt tend to zero faster than dt. (dBt)2 is O(dt) (due to the quadratic variation of a Wiener process which says Bt2=O(t)), so setting (dt)2,dtdBt and (dx)3 terms to zero and substituting dt for (dBt)2, and then collecting the dt terms, we obtain

df=limdt0(ft+μtfx+σt222fx2)dt+σtfxdBt

as required. Alternatively,

df=limdt0(ft+σt222fx2)dt+fxdXt

Geometric intuition

File:Ito lemma 1D illustration.svg
When Xt+dt is a Gaussian random variable, f(Xt+dt) is also approximately Gaussian random variable, but its mean E[f(Xt+dt)] differs from f(E[Xt+dt]) by a factor proportional to f(E[Xt+dt]) and the variance of Xt+dt.

Suppose we know that Xt,Xt+dt are two jointly-Gaussian distributed random variables, and f is nonlinear but has continuous second derivative, then in general, neither of f(Xt),f(Xt+dt) is Gaussian, and their joint distribution is also not Gaussian. However, since Xt+dtXt is Gaussian, we might still find f(Xt+dt)f(Xt) is Gaussian. This is not true when dt is finite, but when dt becomes infinitesimal, this becomes true. The key idea is that Xt+dt=Xt+μtdt+dWt has a deterministic part and a noisy part. When f is nonlinear, the noisy part has a deterministic contribution. If f is convex, then the deterministic contribution is positive (by Jensen's inequality). To find out how large the contribution is, we write Xt+dt=Xt+μtdt+σtdtz, where z is a standard Gaussian, then perform Taylor expansion. f(Xt+dt)=f(Xt)+f(Xt)μtdt+f(Xt)σtdtz+12f(Xt)(σt2z2dt+2μtσtzdt3/2+μt2dt2)+o(dt)=(f(Xt)+f(Xt)μtdt+12f(Xt)σt2dt+o(dt))+(f(Xt)σtdtz+12f(Xt)σt2(z21)dt+o(dt))We have split it into two parts, a deterministic part, and a random part with mean zero. The random part is non-Gaussian, but the non-Gaussian parts decay faster than the Gaussian part, and at the dt0 limit, only the Gaussian part remains. The deterministic part has the expected f(Xt)+f(Xt)μtdt, but also a part contributed by the convexity: 12f(Xt)σt2dt. To understand why there should be a contribution due to convexity, consider the simplest case of geometric Brownian walk (of the stock market): St+dt=St(1+dBt). In other words, d(lnSt)=dBt. Let Xt=lnSt, then St=eXt, and Xt is a Brownian walk. However, although the expectation of Xt remains constant, the expectation of St grows. Intuitively it is because the downside is limited at zero, but the upside is unlimited. That is, while Xt is normally distributed, St is log-normally distributed.

Mathematical formulation of Itô's lemma

In the following subsections we discuss versions of Itô's lemma for different types of stochastic processes.

Itô drift-diffusion processes (due to: Kunita–Watanabe)

In its simplest form, Itô's lemma states the following: for an Itô drift-diffusion process

dXt=μtdt+σtdBt

and any twice differentiable scalar function f(t,x) of two real variables t and x, one has

df(t,Xt)=(ft+μtfx+σt222fx2)dt+σtfxdBt.

This immediately implies that f(t,Xt) is itself an Itô drift-diffusion process. In higher dimensions, if Xt=(Xt1,Xt2,,Xtn)T is a vector of Itô processes such that

dXt=μtdt+GtdBt

for a vector μt and matrix Gt, Itô's lemma then states that

df(t,Xt)=ftdt+(Xf)TdXt+12(dXt)T(HXf)dXt,={ft+(Xf)Tμt+12Tr[GtT(HXf)Gt]}dt+(Xf)TGtdBt

where Xf is the gradient of f w.r.t. X, HX f is the Hessian matrix of f w.r.t. X, and Tr is the trace operator.

Poisson jump processes

We may also define functions on discontinuous stochastic processes. Let h be the jump intensity. The Poisson process model for jumps is that the probability of one jump in the interval [t, t + Δt] is hΔt plus higher order terms. h could be a constant, a deterministic function of time, or a stochastic process. The survival probability ps(t) is the probability that no jump has occurred in the interval [0, t]. The change in the survival probability is

dps(t)=ps(t)h(t)dt.

So

ps(t)=exp(0th(u)du).

Let S(t) be a discontinuous stochastic process. Write S(t) for the value of S as we approach t from the left. Write djS(t) for the non-infinitesimal change in S(t) as a result of a jump. Then

djS(t)=limΔt0(S(t+Δt)S(t))

Let z be the magnitude of the jump and let η(S(t),z) be the distribution of z. The expected magnitude of the jump is

E[djS(t)]=h(S(t))dtzzη(S(t),z)dz.

Define dJS(t), a compensated process and martingale, as

dJS(t)=djS(t)E[djS(t)]=S(t)S(t)(h(S(t))zzη(S(t),z)dz)dt.

Then

djS(t)=E[djS(t)]+dJS(t)=h(S(t))(zzη(S(t),z)dz)dt+dJS(t).

Consider a function g(S(t),t) of the jump process dS(t). If S(t) jumps by Δs then g(t) jumps by Δg. Δg is drawn from distribution ηg() which may depend on g(t), dg and S(t). The jump part of g is

g(t)g(t)=h(t)dtΔgΔgηg()dΔg+dJg(t).

If S contains drift, diffusion and jump parts, then Itô's Lemma for g(S(t),t) is

dg(t)=(gt+μgS+σ222gS2+h(t)Δg(Δgηg()dΔg))dt+gSσdW(t)+dJg(t).

Itô's lemma for a process which is the sum of a drift-diffusion process and a jump process is just the sum of the Itô's lemma for the individual parts.

Non-continuous semimartingales

Itô's lemma can also be applied to general d-dimensional semimartingales, which need not be continuous. In general, a semimartingale is a càdlàg process, and an additional term needs to be added to the formula to ensure that the jumps of the process are correctly given by Itô's lemma. For any cadlag process Yt, the left limit in t is denoted by Yt−, which is a left-continuous process. The jumps are written as ΔYt = YtYt−. Then, Itô's lemma states that if X = (X1, X2, ..., Xd) is a d-dimensional semimartingale and f is a twice continuously differentiable real valued function on Rd then f(X) is a semimartingale, and

f(Xt)=f(X0)+i=1d0tfi(Xs)dXsi+12i,j=1d0tfi,j(Xs)d[Xi,Xj]s+st(Δf(Xs)i=1dfi(Xs)ΔXsi12i,j=1dfi,j(Xs)ΔXsiΔXsj).

This differs from the formula for continuous semi-martingales by the additional term summing over the jumps of X, which ensures that the jump of the right hand side at time t is Δf(Xt).

Multiple non-continuous jump processes

[citation needed]There is also a version of this for a twice-continuously differentiable in space once in time function f evaluated at (potentially different) non-continuous semi-martingales which may be written as follows:

f(t,Xt1,,Xtd)=f(0,X01,,X0d)+0tf˙(s,Xs1,,Xsd)ds+i=1d0tfi(s,Xs1,,Xsd)dXs(c,i)+12i1,,id=1d0tfi1,,id(s,Xs1,,Xsd)dXs(c,i1)Xs(c,id)+0<st[f(s,Xs1,,Xsd)f(s,Xs1,,Xsd)]

where Xc,i denotes the continuous part of the ith semi-martingale.

Examples

Geometric Brownian motion

A process S is said to follow a geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility σ and constant drift μ if it satisfies the stochastic differential equation dSt=σStdBt+μStdt, for a Brownian motion B. Applying Itô's lemma with f(St)=log(St) gives

df=f(St)dSt+12f(St)(dSt)2=1StdSt+12(St2)(St2σ2dt)=1St(σStdBt+μStdt)12σ2dt=σdBt+(μσ22)dt.

It follows that

log(St)=log(S0)+σBt+(μσ22)t,

exponentiating gives the expression for S,

St=S0exp(σBt+(μσ22)t).

The correction term of σ2/2 corresponds to the difference between the median and mean of the log-normal distribution, or equivalently for this distribution, the geometric mean and arithmetic mean, with the median (geometric mean) being lower. This is due to the AM–GM inequality, and corresponds to the logarithm being concave (or convex upwards), so the correction term can accordingly be interpreted as a convexity correction. This is an infinitesimal version of the fact that the annualized return is less than the average return, with the difference proportional to the variance. See geometric moments of the log-normal distribution[broken anchor] for further discussion. The same factor of σ2/2 appears in the d1 and d2 auxiliary variables of the Black–Scholes formula, and can be interpreted as a consequence of Itô's lemma.

Doléans-Dade exponential

The Doléans-Dade exponential (or stochastic exponential) of a continuous semimartingale X can be defined as the solution to the SDE dY = Y dX with initial condition Y0 = 1. It is sometimes denoted by Ɛ(X). Applying Itô's lemma with f(Y) = log(Y) gives

dlog(Y)=1YdY12Y2d[Y]=dX12d[X].

Exponentiating gives the solution

Yt=exp(XtX012[X]t).

Black–Scholes formula

Itô's lemma can be used to derive the Black–Scholes equation for an option.[2] Suppose a stock price follows a geometric Brownian motion given by the stochastic differential equation dS = S(σdB + μ dt). Then, if the value of an option at time t is f(t, St), Itô's lemma gives

df(t,St)=(ft+12(Stσ)22fS2)dt+fSdSt.

The term f/S dS represents the change in value in time dt of the trading strategy consisting of holding an amount f/S of the stock. If this trading strategy is followed, and any cash held is assumed to grow at the risk free rate r, then the total value V of this portfolio satisfies the SDE

dVt=r(VtfSSt)dt+fSdSt.

This strategy replicates the option if V = f(t,S). Combining these equations gives the celebrated Black–Scholes equation

ft+σ2S222fS2+rSfSrf=0.

Product rule for Itô processes

Let Xt be a two-dimensional Ito process with SDE:

dXt=d(Xt1Xt2)=(μt1μt2)dt+(σt1σt2)dBt

Then we can use the multi-dimensional form of Ito's lemma to find an expression for d(Xt1Xt2). We have μt=(μt1μt2) and G=(σt1σt2). We set f(t,Xt)=Xt1Xt2 and observe that Failed to parse (syntax error): {\displaystyle \frac{\partial f}{\partial t}=0,\ (\nabla_\mathbf Xf)^T = (X_t^2\ \ X_t^1)} and HXf=(0110) Substituting these values in the multi-dimensional version of the lemma gives us:

d(Xt1Xt2)=df(t,Xt)=0dt+(Xt2Xt1)dXt+12(dXt1dXt2)(0110)(dXt1dXt2)=Xt2dXt1+Xt1dXt2+dXt1dXt2

This is a generalisation of Leibniz's product rule to Ito processes, which are non-differentiable. Further, using the second form of the multidimensional version above gives us

d(Xt1Xt2)={0+(Xt2Xt1)(μt1μt2)+12Tr[(σt1σt2)(0110)(σt1σt2)]}dt+(Xt2σt1+Xt1σt2)dBt=(Xt2μt1+Xt1μt2+σt1σt2)dt+(Xt2σt1+Xt1σt2)dBt

so we see that the product Xt1Xt2 is itself an Itô drift-diffusion process.

Itô's formula for functions with finite quadratic variation

An idea by Hans Föllmer was to extend Itô's formula to functions with finite quadratic variation.[3] Let fC2 be a real-valued function and x:[0,] a RCLL function with finite quadratic variation. Then

f(xt)=f(x0)+0tf(xs)dxs+12]0,t]f(xs)d[x,x]s+0st(f(xs)f(xs)f(xs)Δxs12f(xs)(Δxs)2)).

Infinite-dimensional formulas

There exist a couple of extensions to infinite-dimensional spaces (e.g. Pardoux,[4] Gyöngy-Krylov,[5] Brzezniak-van Neerven-Veraar-Weis[6]).

See also

Notes

  1. Itô, Kiyoshi (1951). "On a formula concerning stochastic differentials". Nagoya Math. J. 3: 55–65. doi:10.1017/S0027763000012216.
  2. Malliaris, A. G. (1982). Stochastic Methods in Economics and Finance. New York: North-Holland. pp. 220–223. ISBN 0-444-86201-3.
  3. Föllmer, Hans (1981). "Calcul d'Ito sans probabilités". Séminaire de probabilités de Strasbourg. 15: 143–144.
  4. Pardoux, Étienne (1974). "Équations aux dérivées partielles stochastiques de type monotone". Séminaire Jean Leray (3).
  5. Gyöngy, István; Krylov, Nikolay Vladim Vladimirovich (1981). "Ito formula in banach spaces". In M. Arató; D. Vermes, D.; A.V. Balakrishnan (eds.). Stochastic Differential Systems. Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences. Vol. 36. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. pp. 69–73. doi:10.1007/BFb0006409. ISBN 3-540-11038-0.
  6. Brzezniak, Zdzislaw; van Neerven, Jan M. A. M.; Veraar, Mark C.; Weis, Lutz (2008). "Ito's formula in UMD Banach spaces and regularity of solutions of the Zakai equation". Journal of Differential Equations. 245 (1): 30–58. arXiv:0804.0302. doi:10.1016/j.jde.2008.03.026.

References

  • Kiyosi Itô (1944). Stochastic Integral. Proc. Imperial Acad. Tokyo 20, 519–524. This is the paper with the Ito Formula; Online
  • Kiyosi Itô (1951). On stochastic differential equations. Memoirs, American Mathematical Society 4, 1–51. Online
  • Bernt Øksendal (2000). Stochastic Differential Equations. An Introduction with Applications, 5th edition, corrected 2nd printing. Springer. ISBN 3-540-63720-6. Sections 4.1 and 4.2.
  • Philip E Protter (2005). Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations, 2nd edition. Springer. ISBN 3-662-10061-4. Section 2.7.

External links